The Tax Foundation is the nation’s leading independent tax policy research organization. Since 1937, our research, analysis, and experts have informed smarter tax policy at the federal, state, and local levels.
Publishing documents on edocr is a proven way to start demand generation for your products and services. Thousands of professionals and businesses publish marketing (brochures, data sheets, press releases, white papers and case studies), sales (slides, price lists and pro-forma agreements), operations (specifications, operating manuals, installation guides), customer service (user manuals) and financial (annual reports and financial statements) documents making it easier for prospects and customers to find content, helping them to make informed decisions. #SEO #leadgen #content #analytics
About edocr
I am an accomplished content marketing professional helping you to build your brand and business. In my current role, I fulfill a multi-faceted solution marketplace including: publishing and sharing your content, embedding a document viewer on your website, improving your content’s search engine optimization, generating leads with gated content and earning money by selling your documents. I gobble up documents, storing them for safekeeping and releasing the text for excellent search engine optimization, lead generation and earned income.
Publishing documents on edocr.com is a proven way to start demand generation for your products and services. Thousands of professionals and businesses publish marketing, sales, operations, customer service and financial documents making it easier for prospects and customers to find content, helping them to make informed decisions.
Get publishing now!
AN ANALYSIS OF DONALD TRUMP’S TAX PLAN
Jim Nunns, Len Burman, Jeff Rohaly, and Joe Rosenberg
December 22, 2015
ABSTRACT
This paper analyzes presidential candidate Donald Trump’s tax proposal. His plan would significantly reduce
marginal tax rates on individuals and businesses, increase standard deduction amounts to nearly four times
current levels, and curtail many tax expenditures. His proposal would cut taxes at all income levels, although
the largest benefits, in dollar and percentage terms, would go to the highest-income households. The plan
would reduce federal revenues by $9.5 trillion over its first decade before accounting for added interest
costs or considering macroeconomic feedback effects. The plan would improve incentives to work, save, and
invest. However, unless it is accompanied by very large spending cuts, it could increase the national debt by
nearly 80 percent of gross domestic product by 2036, offsetting some or all of the incentive effects of the
tax cuts.
We are grateful to Lily Batchelder, Howard Gleckman, Robert Greenstein, N. Gregory Mankiw, Eric Toder, and Roberton
Williams for helpful comments on earlier drafts. Lydia Austin and Blake Greene prepared the draft for publication and Kathy
Kelly edited it. The authors are solely responsible for any errors. The views expressed do not reflect the views of the Trump
campaign or those who kindly reviewed drafts. The Tax Policy Center is nonpartisan. Nothing in this report should be
construed as an endorsement of or opposition to any campaign or candidate. For information about the Tax Policy Center’s
approach to analyzing candidates’ tax plans, please see http://election2016.taxpolicycenter.org/engagement-policy/.
The findings and conclusions contained within are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect positions or policies of
the Tax Policy Center or its funders.
SUMMARY AND INTRODUCTION
Presidential candidate Donald Trump has proposed tax reforms that would significantly reduce
marginal tax rates for both individuals and businesses, increase standard deduction amounts to
nearly four times current levels, limit or repeal some tax expenditures, repeal the individual and
corporate alternative minimum taxes and the estate and gift taxes, and tax the profits of foreign
subsidiaries of US companies in the year they are earned. The Tax Policy Center estimates the
proposal would reduce federal revenue by $9.5 trillion over its first decade and an additional
$15.0 trillion over the subsequent 10 years, before accounting for added interest costs or
considering macroeconomic feedback effects.1 Most of the revenue loss would come from
individual income tax cuts, but about a third would be from the reduction in the corporate
income tax rate and the introduction of special rates on pass-through businesses.
The proposal would cut taxes at every income level, but high-income taxpayers would
receive the biggest cuts, both in dollar terms and as a percentage of income. Overall, the plan
would cut taxes by an average of about $5,100, or about 7 percent of after-tax income. However,
the highest-income 0.1 percent of taxpayers (those with incomes over $3.7 million in 2015
dollars) would experience an average tax cut of more than $1.3 million in 2017, nearly 19 percent
of after-tax income. Middle-income households would receive an average tax cut of $2,700, or
4.9 percent of after-tax income.
The significant marginal tax rate cuts would boost incentives to work, save, and invest if
interest rates do not change. The plan would also reduce some tax distortions in the allocation of
capital. However, increased government borrowing would push up interest rates and crowd out
private investment, offsetting some or all of the plan’s positive incentive effects. Offsetting a
deficit this large would require unprecedented cuts in federal spending.
The main elements of the Trump proposal, as we modeled them, are listed below.
Appendix A discusses instances in which campaign documents and the candidates’ statements
were unclear and presents the assumptions that we made in our modeling. Note that all of our
estimates reflect the effects of the Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of 2015 and the tax
provisions in the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016 on current law baseline revenues as
well as on the Trump plan.
Individual Income Tax
• Collapse the current seven tax brackets, which range from 10 to 39.6 percent, into three
brackets of 10, 20, and 25 percent.
• Increase the standard deduction to $25,000 for single filers and $50,000 for joint filers in
2015, indexed for inflation thereafter.
• Leave personal exemptions unchanged at $4,000 per person in 2015, indexed.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
1
• Tax dividends and capital gains at a maximum rate of 20 percent.
• Limit the tax value of itemized deductions (other than charitable contributions and
mortgage interest) and exclusions for employer-provided health insurance and tax-exempt
interest.
• Increase the phaseout rates for the personal exemption phaseout and the limit on itemized
deductions.
• Repeal the alternative minimum tax.
• Tax carried interest as ordinary business income.
• Repeal the exclusion for investment income on life insurance contracts entered into after
2016.
Estate and Gift Taxes
• Repeal federal estate and gift taxes.
Business Taxes
• Reduce the corporate tax rate to 15 percent.
• Limit the top individual income tax rate on pass-through businesses such as partnerships to
no more than 15 percent.
• Repeal most tax breaks for businesses.
• Repeal the corporate alternative minimum tax.
• Impose up to a 10 percent deemed repatriation tax on the accumulated profits of foreign
subsidiaries of US companies on the effective date of the proposal, payable over 10 years.
• Tax future profits of foreign subsidiaries of US companies each year as the profits are
earned.
Affordable Care Act Taxes
• Repeal the 3.8 percent net investment income tax on high-income taxpayers (single filers
with income over $200,000 and couples with income over $250,000, unindexed).
MAJOR ELEMENTS OF THE PROPOSAL
Mr. Trump’s stated goals are to provide tax relief for the middle class, simplify the tax code, and
grow the American economy, without adding to the debt or deficit (Trump Campaign 2015).
Individual Income Tax
The plan would reduce the number of individual income tax brackets from the current seven
brackets to three, with rates of 10, 20, and 25 percent (table 1). It would cut the top 39.6 percent
rate by 14.6 percentage points, or more than one-third. The plan would retain current
preferential tax rates of 0, 15, and 20 percent on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
2
The top effective tax rate on capital gains and qualified dividends would fall, however, because
the plan would repeal the 3.8 percent surtax on investment income of high-income taxpayers
that was enacted as part of the Affordable Care Act.
The plan would increase the standard deduction in 2015 from $6,300 to $25,000 for
single filers and from $12,600 to $50,000 for married couples filing jointly, while maintaining
existing personal and dependent exemptions ($4,000 per person in 2015). For nonitemizers, the
Trump plan would reduce taxes throughout the income distribution. The higher standard
deduction would increase the amount of income exempt from tax by $18,700 for single filers and
by $37,400 for joint filers. This income would otherwise be taxed at the taxpayer’s highest
marginal rate.
The number of tax filers who itemize their deductions would decline sharply because of
the higher standard deduction and the limits on itemized deductions, as described below. We
estimate that 39 million (86 percent) of the 45 million filers who would otherwise itemize in 2017
would opt for the standard deduction.
Over
But not over
Over
But not over
0
10,300b
0
0
0
20,600b
0
0
10,300
19,525
10
0
20,600
39,050
10
0
19,525
29,000
15
0
39,050
58,000
15
0
29,000
47,750
15
10
58,000
95,500
15
10
47,750
54,000
25
10
95,500
108,000
25
10
54,000
101,050
25
20
108,000
171,800
25
20
101,050
154,000
28
20
171,800
251,050
28
20
154,000
199,600
28
25
251,050
308,000
33
20
199,600
421,800
33
25
308,000
432,100
33
25
421,800
423,500
35
25
432,100
485,450
35
25
423,500
and over
39.6
25
485,450
and over
39.6
25
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center based on the Trump tax plan and IRS tax brackets.
(a) Tax filers who itemize deductions would not benefit from the Trump tax plan's increase in the standard deduction and would
thus face tax brackets different from those shown in this table.
(b) The lowest tax bracket covers the standard deduction plus personal exemptions: $6,300 + $4,000 for single filers and $12,600
+ $8,000 for childless married couples filing jointly. It does not include the additional standard deduction for elderly or blind
people.
Trump plan
marginal
rate (%)
Single Filers
Childless Married Couples Filing Jointly
Adjusted gross income
($)
Current
marginal
rate (%)
Trump plan
marginal
rate (%)
Adjusted gross income
($)
Current
marginal
rate (%)
TABLE 1
Tax Rates Under Current Law and Under Trump Tax Plan
Among tax filers claiming the standard deduction, 2015a
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
3
The Trump campaign has not specified how it would limit itemized deductions, but we
have assumed the limitations would take the following form, consistent with the general
discussion of the issue in Trump Campaign 2015: First, the tax value of itemized deductions
(other than charitable contributions and mortgage interest) plus the exclusions for employer-
provided health insurance and tax-exempt interest would be subject to a new limitation of 10
percent. Thus, for example, a household in the 20 percent bracket would lose half the value of its
affected itemized deductions and exclusions (table 2). Second, the phaseout rate would double to
6 percent the current-law limit on itemized deductions (often called the Pease limitation on
itemized deductions, after the Ohio representative who helped devise it). Pease currently
reduces itemized deductions (and thereby increases taxable income) by 3 percent of adjusted
gross income (AGI) in excess of $258,250 for single filers and $309,900 for joint filers in 2015.2
We also assume that the plan would double the phaseout rate from 2 percent to 4 percent for the
personal exemption phaseout (PEP), which starts at the same income levels as the limitation on
itemized deductions.3
The Trump plan would reduce the tax incentive to donate to charity. The charitable
deduction under current law reduces the price of giving for itemizers, who can reduce their
taxable income by one dollar for each dollar of giving. For taxpayers in the 39.6 percent bracket,
the after-tax cost of giving a dollar is only 60.4 cents because they save 39.6 cents in taxes for
each dollar given. Although charitable deductions would be exempt from the deduction limit, the
dramatic drop in the number of itemizers would eliminate the tax incentive for charitable giving
for nearly all taxpayers. Most very high-income taxpayers, who account for the bulk of the dollar
value of charitable donations, would continue to itemize and thus still benefit from the
deduction. However, their subsidy would be much lower than today because of the significant
reduction in their tax rates; for taxpayers whose marginal rate is cut to 25 percent, the price of
giving a dollar would rise to 75 cents.
10 percent
20 percent
25 percent
Tax rate (%)
10
20
25
Maximum tax benefit of deduction or
exclusion (%)
10
10
10
Percentage reduction in tax benefit (%)
0
50
60
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center calculations.
Tax Bracket
TABLE 2
Effect of Limiting the Tax Benefit of Certain Itemized
Deductions and Exclusions to 10 Percent
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
4
The proposal would also tax carried interest as ordinary business income (but see below
for a discussion of the overall effects of the proposal on carried interest) and repeal the exclusion
for investment income on life insurance contracts purchased after 2016.
Business Taxes
The plan would reduce the corporate income tax rate from 35 percent to 15 percent and repeal
the corporate alternative minimum tax (AMT). The top rate on pass-through businesses such as
partnerships would also be 15 percent. The plan would eliminate most business tax subsidies. It
would also impose a one-time transition tax of up to 10 percent on existing unrepatriated foreign
income of US companies, payable over 10 years.4 The future profits of foreign subsidiaries of US
companies would be taxed each year as the profits were earned, ending the current law’s
deferral of tax on these profits until they are repatriated.
Establishing a top rate on pass-through business income that is 10 percentage points
below the top rate on wages would create a very strong incentive for wage earners to become
independent contractors, who would be taxed at the preferential pass-through business rates.
Congress could impose strict rules in an attempt to limit such changes in worker status, but the
boundary is quite difficult to enforce under current law and would be even harder to police if the
Trump proposal were enacted. Nevertheless, for purposes of our analysis we have assumed that
such rules would be put in place and be effective. Without such rules, the plan would lose
substantially more revenue than we estimate in this analysis.
Another consequence of the lower top rate on pass-through income is that carried
interest would be taxed at a much lower rate than under current law, notwithstanding its
reclassification as ordinary income (rather than capital gains), because the entities that earn
carried interest income are organized as partnerships. Under current law, such income is taxed as
capital gains, generally at a rate of up to 23.8 percent, including the Affordable Care Act surtax
on investment income. Under the Trump plan, that income would be taxed at a top rate of 15
percent, a reduction of more than one-third.
Large reductions in the corporate rate and the repeal of deferral would reduce the
incentive for firms to recharacterize their domestic income as foreign-source to avoid US tax.
The lower corporate tax rate would also decrease the incentive for a US corporation to move its
tax residence overseas (a so-called corporate inversion). However, ending deferral would
increase the incentive for corporate inversions, offsetting some of the effects of the rate cut.
Estate and Gift Taxes
The plan would repeal federal estate, gift, and generation-skipping taxes. We assume that the
cost basis of inherited assets would continue to be “stepped up” to their value at the time of
death, which would be a more generous provision than the one temporarily enacted when the
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
5
estate and gift tax was temporarily repealed in 2010. Subject to neither estate tax nor capital
gains tax, appreciated property could escape individual level taxation entirely if held until death,
providing an even stronger incentive to hold than under current law.
Revenue Effects
We estimate that the Trump plan would reduce federal receipts by $9.5 trillion between 2016
and 2026 (table 3).5 This decade is the 10-year budget window plus 2016 (in which revenues
would fall slightly because taxpayers would hold off realizing capital gains in expectation of a rate
cut in 2017).6
Three-fourths of the revenue loss would come from individual income tax provisions,
especially the cut in individual income tax rates and the increase in the standard deduction.
Limiting the value of itemized deductions and eliminating certain other preferences would raise
individual income taxes but would offset less than a sixth of the revenue loss from the lower
rates and higher standard deduction.
The business income tax cuts, such as the lowering of corporate and pass-through
business rates and repealing of the corporate AMT, would reduce revenues by about $3.5 trillion
over the decade. Repealing business tax expenditures would recoup about one-quarter of that
loss. Repealing the estate and gift taxes would reduce revenues by an additional $224 billion
over the period.
The revenue loss during the second decade (2027–36) would be more than half again the
first decade’s loss (in nominal terms)—a projected $15.0 trillion. This revenue loss would also
represent a larger share of cumulative GDP—4.2 versus 4.0 percent in 2017–26.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
6
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2016–26
2027–36
Repeal the individual AMT
0.0
-22.7
-31.7
-33.7
-35.1
-36.6
-366.1
-588.3
Repeal the 3.8 percent net investment surtax
-6.7
-0.3
-5.0
-16.1
-19.9
-21.0
-191.8
-355.3
Impose individual income tax rates of 10, 20, and 25 percent
0.0
-231.9
-322.2
-343.1
-365.6
-387.3
-3,946.2
-6,818.9
Impose standard deduction of $25,000/$50,000
0.0
-216.9
-294.1
-302.6
-314.1
-326.6
-3,289.7
-4,805.8
Tax business income at preferential rates
0.0
-59.8
-82.7
-87.6
-92.7
-97.9
-996.9
-1,567.8
Double phaseout rates for Pease and PEP
0.0
8.4
11.8
12.7
13.7
14.5
146.9
263.9
Limit value of certain tax expenditures to 10 percent
0.0
54.7
72.6
77.5
83.0
88.7
909.3
1,652.9
Repeal various business tax expenditures
0.0
14.6
27.8
29.3
30.4
31.6
309.3
449.3
Tax carried interests as ordinary business income
0.0
0.0
-0.1
-0.1
-0.1
-0.1
-0.5
-0.1
Repeal exclusion of investment income on life insurance contracts issued after Dec. 31,
2016
0.0
0.7
2.0
3.5
4.9
6.5
74.5
235.9
Total for individual income tax revenues
-6.7
-453.2
-621.5
-660.1
-695.4
-728.3
-7,351.2
-11,534.2
Repeal the corporate AMT
0.0
-6.6
-13.0
-12.1
-9.9
-8.3
-90.9
-109.9
Reduce corporate rate to flat 15 percent starting in 2017
0.0
-107.8
-215.0
-237.1
-241.6
-249.9
-2,422.3
-3,676.7
End deferral for income of CFCs earned after Dec. 31, 2016
0.0
7.6
15.3
17.1
17.1
17.1
159.6
171.0
Require deemed repatriation over 10 years of accumulated pre-2017 earnings of CFCs,
with reduced rates
0.0
7.1
14.2
15.8
15.8
15.8
147.8
10.3
Repeal various corporate tax expenditures
0.0
7.9
17.4
21.0
22.9
25.3
263.8
490.6
Total for corporate income tax revenues
0.0
-91.8
-181.2
-195.3
-195.7
-200.0
-1,942.0
-3,114.7
Repeal the estate, gift, and GST taxes for deaths and gifts made on or after Jan. 1, 2017
0.0
0.0
-14.8
-22.1
-24.1
-24.9
-223.8
-352.5
Total for estate and gift tax revenues
0.0
0.0
-14.8
-22.1
-24.1
-24.9
-223.8
-352.5
Total revenue change
-6.7
-544.9
-817.4
-877.6
-915.2
-953.3
-9,517.0
-15,001.4
As a percentage of GDP
0.0
-2.8
-4.0
-4.1
-4.1
-4.1
-4.0
-4.2
Sources: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A); TPC estimates.
Note: AMT = alternative minimum tax; CFC = controlled foreign corporation; GDP = gross domestic product; GST = generation skipping tax; Pease = limitation on itemized deductions; PEP = personal exemption
phaseout.
Total revenue effect of all proposals
Provision
Fiscal Year
Individual income tax
Corporate income tax
Estate and gift taxes
TABLE 3
Estimated Effect of Trump Tax Plan on Tax Receipts
$ billions, FY 2016–36
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
7
The revenue losses understate the total effect on the national debt because they do not
include the additional interest that would accrue as a result. Including interest costs, the proposal
would add $11.2 trillion to the national debt by 2026 and $34.1 trillion by 2036 (table 4 and
figure 1). Assuming the tax cuts are not offset by spending cuts, the national debt would rise by
an estimated 39 percent of GDP in 2026 and by nearly 80 percent of GDP by 2036.
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2024
2025
2026 2016–26 2027–36
Revenue loss ($ billions)
6.7
544.9
817.4
877.6
915.2
953.3
990.7 1,033.7 1,080.0 1,123.1 1,174.3
9,517.0 15,001.4
Additional interest ($ billions)
0.1
5.1
24.6
56.7
93.2
133.0
176.1
222.9
272.1
325.9
384.9
1,694.5
7,924.7
Increase in deficit ($ billions)
6.8
550.0
842.0
934.3 1,008.4 1,086.3 1,166.7 1,256.6 1,352.2 1,449.0 1,559.2 11,211.5 22,926.1
Increase in debta ($ billions)
6.8
556.8 1,398.8 2,333.1 3,341.5 4,427.8 5,594.6 6,851.2 8,203.3 9,652.3 11,211.5 11,211.5 34,137.6
Increase in debt relative
to GDP (%)
0.0
2.8
6.8
10.9
15.0
19.0
23.1
27.1
31.1
35.2
39.2
39.2
79.8
Addendum: GDP (end of
period; $ billions)
18,831.9 19,701.4 20,558.3 21,403.7 22,314.7 23,271.0 24,261.5 25,287.4 26,352.1 27,455.5 28,600.0 28,600.0 42,800.0
Fiscal Year
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A); Congressional Budget Office (2015a, 2015b).
(a) Increase in debt equals the cumulative increase in deficit plus additional interest on the debt.
TABLE 4
Effect of Trump Tax Proposal on Federal Revenues, Deficits, and the Debt
FY 2016–36
$0
$200
$400
$600
$800
$1,000
$1,200
$1,400
$1,600
$1,800
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2024
2025
2026
Revenue loss
Additional interest
FIGURE 1
Effects on the Debt
FY 2016–26
$ billions
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A); Congressional Budget Office (2015a, 2015b).
Notes: Increase in debt from 2016 to 2026 is $11,587.1 billion ($9,833.3 billion in revenue loss and $1,753.8 billion in additional interest. Increase in
debt from 2017 to 2036 is $23,720.3 billion ($15,528.2 billion in revenue loss and $8,192.2 billion in additional interest).
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
8
Distributional Effects7
The proposal would reduce taxes throughout the income distribution.8 It would cut taxes
by an average of about $5,100, or about 7 percent of after-tax income (table 5). On average,
households at all income levels would receive tax cuts, but the highest-income households would
receive the largest cuts, both in dollars and as a percentage of income. The highest-income 1.0
percent would get an average tax cut of over $275,000 (17.5 percent of after-tax income), and
the top 0.1 percent would get an average tax cut worth over $1.3 million, nearly 19 percent of
after-tax income. By contrast, the lowest-income households would receive an average tax cut of
$128, or 1 percent of after-tax income. Middle-income households would receive an average tax
cut of about $2,700, or about 5 percent of after-tax income.
Lowest quintile
1.0
0.7
-128
-0.9
3.2
Second quintile
3.1
4.1
-969
-2.8
5.3
Middle quintile
4.9
10.5
-2,732
-4.3
9.2
Fourth quintile
5.8
17.1
-5,369
-4.8
12.1
Top quintile
9.7
67.0
-25,180
-7.2
18.3
All
7.1
100.0
-5,144
-5.7
14.1
Addendum
80–90
5.4
10.6
-7,731
-4.3
15.4
90–95
5.7
7.6
-11,476
-4.5
17.2
95–99
8.5
13.8
-27,657
-6.4
18.7
Top 1 percent
17.5
35.0
-275,257
-11.8
21.1
Top 0.1 percent
18.9
17.0
-1,302,887
-12.5
21.8
(e) Average federal tax (includes individual and corporate income tax, payroll taxes for Social Security and Medicare, the estate
tax, and excise taxes) as a percentage of average expanded cash income.
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A).
Notes: Number of Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) taxpayers (millions). Baseline: 4.5; Proposal: 0.
(a) Projections are for calendar year 2017; baseline is current law (including provisions in the Protecting Americans from Tax
Hikes Act of 2015 and the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016). The proposal includes all individual, corporate, and estate
tax provisions. http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxtopics/Baseline-Definitions.cfm.
(b) The percentile includes both filing and non-filing units but excludes units that are dependents of other tax units. Tax units with
negative adjusted gross income are excluded from their respective income class, but they are included in the totals. For a
description of expanded cash income, see http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/income.cfm.
(c) The income percentile classes used in this table are based on the income distribution for the entire population and contain
an equal number of people, not tax units. The breaks are (in 2015 dollars) 20% $23,099; 40% $45,153; 60% $80,760; 80%
$142,601; 90% $209,113; 95% $295,756; 99% $732,323; 99.9% $3,769,396.
(d) After-tax income is expanded cash income less individual income tax net of refundable credits, corporate income tax, payroll
taxes (Social Security and Medicare), estate tax, and excise taxes.
Expanded cash
income
percentileb,c
Percent change
in after-tax
income (%) d
Share of total
federal tax
change (%)
Average
federal tax
change ($)
Average Federal Tax Ratee
Change (%
points)
Under the
proposal (%)
TABLE 5
Distribution of Federal Tax Change
By expanded cash income percentile, 2017a
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
9
The proposal would provide even larger nominal tax cuts in 2025—averaging nearly
$6,600. However, those tax cuts would represent a slightly smaller share (6.9 percent) of after-
tax income (table 6 and figure 2). The highest-income households (0.1 percent) would receive an
average tax cut of nearly $1.8 million, over 18 percent of after-tax income. Lower-income
households would receive modest tax cuts relative to current law.
On balance, the plan would significantly increase the number of households that would
pay no income tax (or would receive an income tax refund). In 2017, an estimated 110 million
households would pay no income tax under the plan, compared with 77 million under current
law. That would boost the percentage of households paying no income tax from 44 percent to 63
percent.
Lowest quintile
1.1
0.8
-209
-1.1
3.4
Second quintile
3.1
4.5
-1,323
-2.8
5.9
Middle quintile
4.9
11.1
-3,621
-4.2
10.0
Fourth quintile
5.2
15.7
-6,210
-4.3
12.9
Top quintile
9.5
67.3
-32,276
-7.0
19.2
All
6.9
100.0
-6,594
-5.5
14.8
Addendum
80–90
4.6
9.0
-8,391
-3.7
16.4
90–95
4.8
6.2
-11,778
-3.8
17.9
95–99
7.8
12.3
-31,582
-5.9
19.2
Top 1 percent
17.6
39.8
-407,375
-11.7
21.8
Top 0.1 percent
18.3
18.0
-1,780,826
-12.0
22.3
(e) Average federal tax (includes individual and corporate income tax, payroll taxes for Social Security and Medicare, the estate
tax, and excise taxes) as a percentage of average expanded cash income.
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A).
Notes: Number of Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) taxpayers (millions). Baseline: 5; Proposal: 0.
(a) Projections are for calendar year 2025; baseline is current law (including provisions in the Protecting Americans from Tax
Hikes Act of 2015 and the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016). The proposal includes all individual, corporate, and estate
tax provisions. http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxtopics/Baseline-Definitions.cfm.
(b) The percentile includes both filing and non-filing units but excludes units that are dependents of other tax units. Tax units with
negative adjusted gross income are excluded from their respective income class, but they are included in the totals. For a
description of expanded cash income, see http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/income.cfm.
(c) The income percentile classes used in this table are based on the income distribution for the entire population and contain
an equal number of people, not tax units. The breaks are (in 2015 dollars) 20% $26,101; 40% $51,178; 60% $87,777; 80%
$148,458; 90% $217,212; 95% $289,677; 99% $846,843; 99.9% $5,205,348.
(d) After-tax income is expanded cash income less individual income tax net of refundable credits, corporate income tax payroll
taxes (Social Security and Medicare), estate tax, and excise taxes.
Expanded cash
income
percentileb,c
Percent change
in after-tax
income (%)d
Share of total
federal tax
change (%)
Average
federal tax
change ($)
Average Federal Tax Ratee
Change (%
points)
Under the
proposal (%)
TABLE 6
Distribution of Federal Tax Change
By expanded cash income percentile, 2025a
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
10
The financing of the tax cuts would ultimately affect the distribution of winners and losers
in ways that are hard to predict. Although a portion of the revenue loss might be offset by higher
tax revenues resulting from increased economic growth, the remainder of the financing would
have to come from some combination of spending cuts and tax increases. If the tax cuts are
financed by broad spending cuts, the net effects of the plan are likely to be regressive, since the
benefits of government spending tend to be distributed progressively (Elmendorff et al. 2008). If
the resulting deficits ultimately are paid for by restoring higher taxes, and the tax increases are
concentrated at the top of income distribution, the long-run effect could be more progressive
(although this would entail economic costs, as discussed below).
COMPLEXITY
Mr. Trump’s plan would simplify the tax code in several ways, but it would also create some new
complexities. By significantly increasing the standard deduction and limiting or eliminating many
tax expenditures, the plan would reduce record-keeping and reporting requirements and reduce
the number of itemizers by 39 million (an 86 percent reduction) in 2017. Overall, the share of
filers who itemize in 2017 would fall from 31 percent under current law to 4 percent, although
that number would creep upward over time as incomes rise (as would also happen under current
law). Eliminating the complex AMT and the Affordable Care Act surcharge on net investment
0
5
10
15
20
25
Lowest
quintile
Second
quintile
Middle
quintile
Fourth
quintile
Top
quintile
All
80–90
90–95
95–99
Top 1
percent
Top 0.1
percent
Change (%)
2017
2025
FIGURE 2
Percent Change in After-Tax Income Under Trump Proposal
By expanded cash income percentile, 2017 and 2025
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A).
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
11
income would also simplify tax preparation. For businesses, the proposal would eliminate special
tax provisions that complicate record keeping and tax preparation.
Some elements of the plan could add complexity, however. For example, it would require
new rules to prevent wage earners from switching to independent contractor status to benefit
from the more favorable rates on business income. The limitation on the value of certain itemized
deductions and exclusions would require many taxpayers to perform two sets of calculations to
decide whether to itemize. Software could simplify these calculations, but this new limitation
would make it harder for taxpayers to understand exactly how the tax system affects them.
Ending deferral could introduce new complexities for companies with foreign subsidiaries.
ECONOMIC EFFECTS
Impact on Saving and Investment
The Trump plan would alter incentives to save and invest in the United States. Large reductions
in the tax rate on corporate and pass-through business profits, lower effective marginal tax rates
on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends for most taxpayers with such income, and
much lower rates on interest income throughout the income distribution would all increase the
after-tax return to savers (table 7). Assuming that interest rates do not change (see discussion
below) and the tax cuts are not eventually financed in ways that reduce incentives to save and
invest, these effects would tend to increase the amount of saving and investment in the US
economy.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
12
The overall effect of taxes on incentives to save and invest can be summarized in the
marginal effective tax rate (METR). METR is a forward-looking measure of the impact of the tax
system on the rate of return of a hypothetical marginal (i.e., just break-even) investment project.9
We compare the METR on different investments under the Trump proposal with the METR
under current law, including the provisions of the Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of
2015 and the tax provisions in the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016. The Trump
proposal would generally impose much lower METRs than current law (table 8).
Lowest quintile
47,878
0.8
0.4
-0.3
0.3
0.2
-0.1
2.8
1.1
-1.7
Second quintile
37,992
1.3
0.6
-0.7
0.9
0.4
-0.5
6.1
1.0
-5.2
Middle quintile
34,342
6.3
5.0
-1.3
7.5
5.3
-2.2
18.3
8.1
-10.2
Fourth quintile
28,545
9.8
9.0
-0.8
11.0
10.6
-0.4
21.9
15.1
-6.9
Top quintile
23,785
22.6
19.0
-3.6
22.0
18.8
-3.2
34.7
23.0
-11.7
All
173,829
20.7
17.5
-3.2
18.8
16.2
-2.6
27.4
17.9
-9.5
Addendum
80–90
12,240
12.2
13.0
0.8
14.1
15.1
1.1
25.1
19.5
-5.6
90–95
5,942
14.2
13.3
-0.9
16.4
15.6
-0.8
28.1
20.3
-7.8
95–99
4,468
19.6
15.6
-4.0
22.6
17.7
-4.9
35.5
22.1
-13.4
Top 1 percent
1,135
23.9
20.0
-3.9
24.0
20.1
-3.9
37.5
24.4
-13.1
Top 0.1 percent
116
24.1
20.2
-3.9
24.0
20.3
-3.7
36.8
24.6
-12.1
Change
(percentage
points)
Current
law
Change
(percentage
points)
Trump
proposal
Qualified Dividends
Trump
proposal
Long-Term Capital Gains
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A).
(a) Projections are for calendar year 2017. Effective marginal tax rates are weighted by the appropriate income source.
(b) Includes both filing and non-filing units but excludes units that are dependents of other tax units. Tax units with negative adjusted gross income are excluded
from their respective income class, but they are included in the totals. For a description of expanded cash income, see
http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/income.cfm.
(c) The income percentile classes used in this table are based on the income distribution for the entire population and contain an equal number of people, not tax
units. The breaks are (in 2015 dollars) 20% $23,099; 40% $45,153; 60% $80,760; 80% $142,601; 90% $209,113; 95% $295,756; 99% $732,323; 99.9%
$3,769,396.
Expanded cash
income
percentileb,c
Tax units
(thousands)
Interest Income
Current
law
Current
law
Change
(percentage
points)
Trump
proposal
TABLE 7
Effective Marginal Individual Income Tax Rates on Capital Income
In percent, 2017a
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
13
The Trump proposal would lower the overall METR on nonresidential business
investment by 9.4 percentage points, from 23.2 to 13.8 percent, a reduction of 41 percent. As
under the current tax system, pass-through businesses would face a lower METR (10.9 percent)
than would traditional C corporations (15.5 percent) owing to the lack of a second layer of tax on
equity at the individual level.
The proposal would also make business taxation more uniform in several dimensions.
METRs for equity-financed corporate investments would decline from 32.5 to 18.9 percent,
while the METR on debt-financed corporate investment would rise from -6.2 to 4.8 percent
(mainly owing to the reduced value of interest deductibility with a lower corporate tax rate). The
proposal would also significantly reduce the variation in METRs across assets and industries.
Research and development (R&D) would continue to receive preferential treatment because
Business investment
23.2
13.8
-9.4
Corporate
25.7
15.5
-10.2
Equipment
21.6
13.4
-8.2
Structures
29.5
17.2
-12.3
Intellectual property products
1.3
4.2
2.9
Inventories
39.8
22.2
-17.6
Pass-through
19.1
10.9
-8.2
Equipment
15.8
8.8
-7.0
Structures
22.4
12.9
-9.5
Intellectual property products
-3.3
-2.7
0.6
Inventories
31.9
18.8
-13.1
Addendum
Corporate (equity financed)
32.5
18.9
-13.6
Corporate (debt financed)
-6.2
4.8
11.0
Variation (s.d.) across assets
12.8
6.8
Variation (s.d.) across industries
6.4
3.4
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center calculations. See Rosenberg and Marron (2015) for discussion.
Notes: s.d. = standard deviation. Estimates for are calendar year 2017; the baseline is current law and includes
the effect of provisions passed as part of the Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of 2015 and the
Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016.
Category
Current
law
Change
(percentage points)
Trump
proposal
TABLE 8
Marginal Effective Tax Rates on New Investment
In percent, 2017
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
14
such spending is generally expensed and often eligible for the research and experimentation
credit, but METRs on R&D would be slightly higher than under current law (due to the higher
rate on debt financed investments). More equal tax treatment across assets and financing
arrangements should reduce the role of taxation in investment decisions, allowing investment to
flow to projects with a higher social return rather than those with the most favorable tax status.
Our estimates of effects on investment incentives assume the Trump plan would not
affect the overall level of interest rates and would not eventually be paid for by spending cuts or
tax increases that reduce investment incentives. However, large reductions in federal revenues
that are not offset by some combination of spending cuts or increased revenues from higher
economic activity are likely to drive up interest rates. Higher interest rates and/or future
spending cuts or tax increases could negate some or all of the reduction in the cost of capital
arising from the tax changes (Gale and Orszag 2005).
Impact on Labor Supply
The proposal would also cut effective tax rates on labor income (i.e., wages and salaries for
employees and self-employment income for others). EMTRs on labor income would be reduced
by an average of 7.6 percentage points and by over 14 percentage points for the top 0.1 percent
(table 9). Research suggests that taxes play a small or negligible role on labor supply decisions for
most workers. When tax rates fall, some workers choose to work more because the reward for
working rises, but some choose to work less because it is easier to meet consumption goals with
higher take-home pay.
Second earners—lower-earning spouses—are sensitive to taxes, however. A person
married to a high earner might face a very high marginal tax rate on the first dollar of earnings,
which, when combined with the costs of working (e.g., paying for child care), can make working
seem especially unappealing. By reducing marginal tax rates, the proposal would reduce the
disincentive for entering the workforce for potential second earners.
Macroeconomic Effects
Gale and Samwick (2014) discuss the impact of an income tax cut on the long-term growth rate of
the economy. They suggest that the potential effects of a change in the individual income tax can
be broken into four parts. The first effect—known as the substitution effect—is that lower tax
rates increase incentives to work, save, and invest.
A second effect—the income effect—tends to offset the first, however. Tax cuts raise the
after-tax return to labor, saving, and investment, which makes it easier to reach consumption
targets, such as paying for college or retirement. Because taxpayers feel richer, some decide to
work, save, or invest less.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
15
The third effect of tax reform stems from whether financing mechanisms are primarily
spending cuts or increased federal borrowing. If the immediate revenue loss from a tax cut is not
offset with spending reductions, the higher federal deficits reduce net national saving. Increased
federal borrowing crowds out private investment, raising interest rates and the cost of capital
and depressing economic growth. As noted earlier, the deficits arising from this plan are so large
that offsetting spending cuts may be politically infeasible.10
The fourth effect stems from base broadening. Broadening the base by reining in
distortionary tax expenditures reduces the role of taxation in determining the allocation of
resources across the economy, which in turn can increase economic output. However, Gravelle
and Marples (2015) point out that some tax expenditures tend to increase with income, meaning
Lowest quintile
47,878
1.7
-2.9
-4.7
15.6
10.9
-4.7
Second quintile
37,992
15.7
7.0
-8.6
29.5
20.8
-8.6
Middle quintile
34,342
19.0
11.2
-7.8
32.6
24.7
-7.8
Fourth quintile
28,545
19.9
14.5
-5.4
33.4
28.0
-5.4
Top quintile
23,785
31.0
22.4
-8.6
38.1
29.5
-8.6
All
173,829
24.6
16.9
-7.6
34.8
27.1
-7.6
Addendum
80–90
12,240
25.3
20.6
-4.7
35.9
31.2
-4.7
90–95
5,942
27.6
20.7
-6.9
35.4
28.5
-6.9
95–99
4,468
33.2
23.6
-9.5
38.6
29.0
-9.5
Top 1 percent
1,135
39.0
24.7
-14.3
42.9
28.7
-14.3
Top 0.1 percent
116
39.3
24.8
-14.5
43.1
28.6
-14.5
(a) Projections are for calendar year 2017. Effective marginal tax rates are weighted by the wages and salaries.
Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model (version 0515-3A).
(b) Includes both filing and nonfiling units but excludes units that are dependents of other tax units. Tax units with negative
adjusted gross income are excluded from their respective income class, but they are included in the totals. For a description of
expanded cash income, see http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/income.cfm.
(c) The income percentile classes used in this table are based on the income distribution for the entire population and contain
an equal number of people, not tax units. The breaks are (in 2015 dollars) 20% $23,099; 40% $45,153; 60% $80,760; 80%
$142,601; 90% $209,113; 95% $295,756; 99% $732,323; 99.9% $3,769,396.
Change
(percentage
points)
Expanded cash
income
percentileb,c
Tax units
(thousands)
Individual Income Tax
Individual Income Tax and
Payroll Taxes
Current
law
Trump
proposal
Change
(percentage
points)
Current
law
Trump
proposal
TABLE 9
Effective Marginal Individual Income Tax Rates on Wages,
Salaries, and Self-Employment Income
In percent, 2017a
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
16
that base broadening can increase effective marginal tax rates on an additional dollar of earnings
by raising the cost of some goods and services purchased with the earnings. For example, state
income taxes tend to increase with income. Thus, the deductibility of state taxes reduces the
marginal effective income tax rate. Limiting the deduction, as the Trump proposal would do,
would therefore tend to increase effective marginal rates.
The actual effect of tax cuts is an empirical question, and researchers have applied many
methods to estimate the impact.11 Examination of particular historical examples of tax reform—
including shifts between the pre– and post–World War II periods, and the tax changes that
occurred in 1981, 1986, 2001, and 2003—suggest little impact of taxes on growth. Simulation
models imply that deficit-financed tax cuts are less effective at promoting growth than tax cuts
financed by cutting unproductive government spending (Auerbach and Slemrod 1997; Dennis et
al. 2004; Desai and Goolsbee 2004; Gale and Potter 2002). Cross-country comparisons of
changes in output and changes in top marginal tax rates suggest little or no impact of taxes on
growth (Piketty, Saez, and Stantcheva 2014).
One challenge in estimating the effect of taxes on the economy is that tax changes are
endogenous: for example, policymakers may choose to enact tax cuts when the economy is weak,
which would lead to large apparent growth responses, or they might cut taxes when the economy
is strong and revenues are surging, which would produce the opposite response. Romer and
Romer (2010) identified plausibly exogenous US tax reforms in time-series data and measured a
positive effect of net tax cuts on economic activity. Although Romer and Romer could not
distinguish short-term demand-side responses from more permanent supply-side responses,
some recent research (Barro and Redlick 2011; Mertens 2015) finds evidence that it is a supply-
side effect.12
The Trump plan would require unprecedented spending cuts to avoid adding to the
federal debt. We estimate that the plan would reduce revenues by $1.1 trillion in 2025 (before
considering macroeconomic effects).
The Congressional Budget Office (2015a) projects total noninterest outlays in 2025 of
about $5.3 trillion. As a result, Congress would need to cut projected program spending by 21
percent to prevent the plan from adding to the deficit in 2025. If Congress eliminated all defense
spending (about $0.7 billion), it could not meet this goal. It would need to cut discretionary
spending by 82 percent or Medicare and Social Security spending by 41 percent to offset the
direct revenue loss.
As in the distributional analysis discussed above, financing of the tax cuts can have
important effects on the long-run macroeconomic results. If spending were cut enough to offset
most of the revenue losses, the economy would grow. A 2006 US Treasury study concluded that
financing the permanent extension of the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts by cutting spending would
raise GNP by 0.1 to 1.2 percent, depending on how responsive labor supply and saving are to tax
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
17
rates (US Treasury 2006). However, if spending were not cut and the growing deficits ultimately
led to tax rate increases, the same study found that GNP would fall by 0.9 percent in the long
run. The experience of the past three decades suggests that large tax cuts that widen the deficit
are not necessarily followed by spending cuts, but instead may ultimately require future tax
increases.13 If that pattern were repeated after enacting the Trump tax cuts, total economic
output could ultimately be smaller than if the tax cuts had not been enacted in the first place.
Barring politically difficult spending cuts or tax increases, the Trump tax cuts would
produce deficits of as much as $11.2 trillion over the next decade, which could swamp any
salutary effects arising from lowering marginal effective tax rates on work, saving, and
investment. We estimate that by 2036, with no change in spending or interest rates, the proposal
would raise the national debt by nearly 80 percent of GDP. If interest rates rise in response to
the burgeoning public debt, the increase in the debt could be much larger.
CONCLUSIONS
Mr. Trump’s tax reform plan would boost incentives to work, save, and invest, and has the
potential to simplify the tax code. By lowering marginal tax rates and further limiting or repealing
many tax expenditures, it would reduce the incentives and opportunities to engage in some
forms of wasteful tax avoidance. However, the plan could increase incentives for workers to
characterize themselves as independent contractors, to take advantage of the lower tax rate on
business income, unless new rules were introduced to prevent this. The proposal would cut taxes
on households at every income level, but much more as a share of income at the top. The
fundamental concern the plan poses is that, barring extraordinarily large cuts in government
spending or future tax increases, it would yield persistently large, and likely unsustainable,
budget deficits.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
18
APPENDIX A. UNCLEAR DETAILS AND TPC’S ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT THE TRUMP PLAN
Because candidates’ proposals rarely include all the details needed to model them accurately, we
ask their staffs to clarify provisions or further specify details. Unfortunately, we did not receive
any response to our attempts to contact the Trump campaign, so we were unable to obtain
clarifications of provisions that are unclear or not fully specified in the Trump tax plan.
In the absence of such clarifications, we based our assumptions on Mr. Trump’s
statements, documents released by the campaign (see Trump Campaign 2015), and the Tax
Foundation’s September 29 analysis (Cole 2015). We note that Mr. Trump has taken issue with
the Tax Foundation’s analysis, but it is unclear what specifically the campaign disagrees with
(other than the conclusions).
What follow are the issues (I) we identified in the available materials that we believed
required clarification or further specification. We follow each issue with the assumptions (A) we
made in our modeling of the Trump plan in the absence of guidance from the campaign.
1. Individual Income Tax
I1. The documentation shows a zero percent tax rate for single filers on income up to
$25,000 (married couples up to $50,000 and heads of household up to $37,500). It is unclear
whether this provision is intended to reinstate a zero bracket amount, with those specific values,
similar to the zero bracket that existed prior to the 1986 tax reform, or is simply intended to
represent increased standard deduction amounts.
A1. We assume standard deduction amounts are increased to those values.
I2. It is unclear whether the values in the documentation’s tax table are expressed in 2015
dollars or in the dollars of some other year.
A2. We assume the values in the tax table are expressed in 2015 dollars and are indexed
for inflation going forward as in current law.
I3. It is unclear precisely how the proposal would tax the income from sole proprietorships
and pass-through entities such as partnerships and S-corporations at the individual level.
A3. We assume that income from sole proprietorships and pass-through entities would be
taxed using a preferential rate schedule in a manner similar to the way in which current law
applies preferential rates to long-term capital gains and qualified dividends. Business income
otherwise taxed at 10 percent would continue to be taxed at 10 percent, but business income
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
19
otherwise taxed at 20 percent or 25 percent would be taxed at 15 percent. We assume that
business losses would only reduce tax at these same rates.
I4. The proposal does not mention any legislation or regulations to prevent taxpayers
from recharacterizing wage and salary or other income as income eligible for the preferential
individual income tax rates on business income.
A4. We assume that some effective rules would be adopted to prevent such shifting
between ordinary income and business income.
I5. The documentation states that the maximum tax rate on long-term capital gains and
qualified dividends is 20 percent. This appears to mean that the proposal repeals the 3.8 percent
net investment income tax originally enacted by the Affordable Care Act.
A5. We assume the proposal repeals the 3.8 percent net investment income tax.
I6. The documentation states that charitable and mortgage interest deductions will
remain unchanged for all taxpayers, but also states that with lower rates most exemptions and
deductions would become redundant. Those within the 10 percent bracket would keep most of
their deductions, those within the 20 percent bracket would keep more than half their
deductions, and those within the 25 percent bracket would keep fewer deductions. No specific
mechanisms for achieving these results are specified.
A6. We assume that the tax benefits of itemized deductions (other than charitable and
mortgage interest), and the exemptions for employer-provided health benefits and tax-exempt
interest, would be limited to 10 percent of the deduction or exemption.
I7. The documentation states that the proposal would keep the charitable and mortgage
interest deductions unchanged for all taxpayers, but it would “steepen the curve” of the Pease
limitation on itemized deductions. Under current law, both the charitable and mortgage interest
deductions are subject to the Pease limitation, so it is unclear how the limitation would be
altered.
A7. We assume that the proposal simply doubles the Pease phaseout rate from 3 percent
to 6 percent.
I8. The documentation states that the proposal would steepen the curve of the personal
exemption phaseout (PEP). How this would be accomplished is not specified.
A8. We assume that the proposal simply doubles the PEP phaseout rate from 2 percent to
4 percent.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
20
I9. The documentation states that the proposal would phase out the tax exemption on life
insurance interest for high-income earners. How the phaseout would work is not specified.
A9. We assume that the exclusion is eliminated prospectively on all new life insurance
contracts.
I10. The documentation states that the proposal would reduce or eliminate “other
loopholes for the very rich and special interests” but does not specify which loopholes or how
they would be reduced or eliminated.
A10. In the absence of specific guidance, we were unable to model the reduction or repeal
of any other loopholes.
I11. It is unclear whether the proposal would retain the permanent extensions made in the
Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of 2015 to provisions of the earned income tax credit
(EITC) and the child tax credit (CTC), and retention of the American Opportunity Tax Credit
(AOTC) to the HOPE credit.
A11. We assume that the proposal retains these permanent extensions.
I12. It is unclear whether the proposal allows other would retain other extensions made in
the Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of 2015 and the tax provisions in the Consolidated
Appropriations Act of 2016.
A12. We assume that the proposal retains these other extensions, except as noted in A20
below, but that none of the temporary extensions would be further extended.
I13. It is unclear whether the plan includes any other changes to exclusions, above-the-
line deductions, or credits that are not specified in the plan description.
A13. We assume that the plan proposes no other changes to exclusions, above-the-line
deductions, or credits.
2. Estate and Gift Taxes
I14. The documentation states that the proposal would repeal the “death tax.” It is unclear
whether this specifically means that the proposal would repeal the federal estate, gift, and
generation-skipping transfer (GST) taxes, whether these taxes would be replaced with any form
of tax on inherited wealth, or whether the step-up in basis would be replaced with any form of
carryover-basis regime on inherited assets.
A14. We assume the proposal repeals the federal estate, gift, and GST taxes and does not
institute any other form of tax on inherited wealth. We also assume the proposal would retain
unlimited step-up in basis for inherited assets.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
21
3. Affordable Care Act Provisions
I15. It is unclear whether the proposal repeals any of the tax provisions enacted by the
Affordable Care Act other than the 3.8 percent net investment income tax, such as the 0.9
percent surcharge on earnings or the excise tax on high-cost health plans (the “Cadillac Tax”).
A15. We assume the Trump tax proposal does not repeal any of the other tax provisions
enacted by the Affordable Care Act. (If Mr. Trump subsequently releases a detailed health care
proposal in which those provisions are explicitly repealed, we will update our analysis
accordingly.)
4. Business Provisions
I16. The proposal states that it would “phase in a reasonable cap on the deductibility of
business interest expenses,” but it does not specify how the cap would work.
A16. Absent further detail, we were unable to model the cap on interest deductibility.
I17. It is unclear whether the plan would make any changes to the foreign tax credit rules
associated with ending deferral of tax on foreign-earned corporate income.
A17. We assume that the rules under the current law continue to apply.
I18. It is unclear whether the one-time repatriation tax is similar to the Camp proposal, so
the 10 percent rate applies only to accumulated untaxed CFC earnings held in cash and a lower
rate to the remainder, or whether the one-time tax is payable immediately or over some number
of years.
A18. We assume that the one-time repatriation tax is structured in the same manner as
the Camp proposal, with the 10 percent rate applying to accumulated cash earnings and a lower
4 percent rate applying to noncash earnings (resulting in the same proportional difference
between the 8.75 and 3.5 percent rates in the Camp plan), and the payments would be made over
10 years (rather than 8).
I19. It is unclear whether the 15 percent rate is a flat tax rate on all corporate income, or
whether some form of graduated rate schedule is maintained.
A19. We assume the corporate rate is a flat 15 percent.
I20. It is unclear which specific business tax preferences would be eliminated.
A20. We assume that the plan repeals the following provisions:
a. Inventory property sales source exemption
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
22
b. Tax credits for alternative energy production and investment, energy
conservation, and investments in energy-efficient property
c. Percentage depletion
d. Exclusion of interest on private-purpose tax-exempt bonds
e. Tax incentives for preservation of historic structures
f. Exemption of credit union income
g. Exclusion of interest on life insurance savings
h. Tax exemption of insurance companies owned by tax-exempt organizations
i. Small life insurance company deduction
j. Credit for low-income housing investments
k. Deduction for US production activities
l. Other targeted incentives for community and regional development
m. Tax credit for orphan drug research
n. Special Blue Cross Blue Shield deduction
o. Tax benefits for employee stock ownership plans (ESOPs)
p. Employer wage credit for activated military reservists
q. Minimum LIHTC rate for non-Federally subsidized new buildings
r. 15-year straight-line cost recovery for qualified leasehold improvements
s. Exception under subpart F for active financing income
t. Look-through treatment of payments between related CFCs
u. Independent refiner exclusion of 75% of oil transportation costs for Section 199
deduction
Note: Items p through u were included in the Protecting Americans from Tax Hikes Act of
2015 or the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2016.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
23
5. Effective Date
I21. It is unclear whether all provisions are intended to go into effect in 2017 or at some
earlier (or later) date, or whether some provisions are phased in over time.
A21. We assume the provisions would be effective for the 2017 tax year, after the
presidential election, and that no provisions would be phased in gradually over time.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
24
APPENDIX B. COMPARISON OF TPC REVENUE ESTIMATES WITH OTHER PUBLISHED ESTIMATES
Our revenue estimates differ from other published estimates of the revenue cost of Donald
Trump’s tax proposal (table B1). TPC’s 10-year revenue cost ($9.5 trillion) is smaller than the
estimates released by Citizens for Tax Justice (CTJ 2015) and by the Tax Foundation (Cole
2015), which both estimate the revenue cost as $12.0 trillion.
These differences cannot be fully reconciled based on the level of detail published. One
difference is the assumed starting date of the Trump proposal: the Tax Foundation uses 2015,
CTJ uses 2016, and TPC uses 2017. The later TPC starting date, in itself, should make the TPC
estimate larger than the others. TPC’s estimates reflect the effects of the Protecting Americans
from Tax Hikes Act of 2015 and the tax provisions in the Consolidated Appropriations Act of
2016 on baseline revenues under current law as well as on the provisions in the Trump plan,
which somewhat reduces the cost of the plan, whereas the analyses by the CTJ and the Tax
Foundation were made prior to enactment of these Acts.
The TPC estimates are also smaller in part because the other analyses do not estimate
some of the revenue-raising provisions that TPC estimated. For example, the Tax Foundation did
not estimate the revenue effect of ending deferral (which TPC estimates would raise $160 billion
through 2026), and CTJ appears not to have estimated the revenue effect of repealing any
business tax preferences (which TPC estimates would raise $573 billion through 2026). We may
also have made different assumptions about how cutbacks to individual tax preferences would
Individual
N/A
-10,201
-7,351
Corporate
N/A
-1,541
-1,942
Estate
N/A
-238
-224
Total
-12,000
-11,980
-9,517
Tax
Foundation
2015–24
Sources: Citizens for Tax Justice (2015); Cole (2015); and Urban-Brookings Tax
Policy Center calculations.
Note: N/A = not available.
Citizens for
Tax Justice
2016-2025
Tax Policy
Center
2016–26
TABLE B1
Tax Policy Center Revenue Estimates
for the Trump Proposal Compared
with Other Public Estimates
$ billions
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
25
work, which affects how much money they would raise. (These provisions of the proposal are not
well specified, so each group had to make specific assumptions to estimate the effect of these
provisions.) No detail on the revenue gains from these provisions is available from either CTJ or
the Tax Foundation; TPC’s estimates include a revenue gain of nearly $1.1 trillion through 2026
from the doubling of the Pease and PEP phaseout rates and a new limitation on the tax benefit of
certain itemized deductions and exclusions.
A further difference could result from how the $25,000 allowance for single filers and
$50,000 for joint filers was modeled. TPC treated these as new standard deduction amounts,
which has the effect of substantially reducing the number of itemizers and itemized deductions.
The Tax Foundation apparently treated these as “zero bracket amounts” (that embed the current
standard deduction amounts), which would not directly reduce itemization or itemized
deductions and therefore have a much larger revenue cost. CTJ refers to these amounts as
standard deductions, but it may have modeled them in a manner similar to the Tax Foundation’s.
We estimate that over 10 years the Tax Foundation’s approach to this provision would cost $1.7
trillion more than our approach.
Differences could also arise from different baselines or modeling differences, such as
alternative assumptions about how responsive taxpayers are to changes in tax rates. Our
baseline is calibrated to match the Congressional Budget Office (2015a, 2015b) projections, and
our estimates of the responsiveness of taxpayers to changes in tax rates are designed to match as
closely as possible official congressional estimates produced by the Joint Committee on
Taxation.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION
26
APPENDIX C. MEASURING DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF TAX CHANGES
Analysts use a variety of measures to assess the distributional effects of tax changes. There is no
perfect measure—often a combination of measures is more informative than any single measure.
The Tax Policy Center generally focuses on the percentage change in after-tax income
because it measures the gain or loss of income available to households to buy goods and services,
relative to the amount available before the tax change. A tax change that raises or lowers after-
tax income by the same percentage for all households